A History of Economic Doctrines from the time of the physiocrats to the present day. Charles Gide. Читать онлайн. Newlib. NEWLIB.NET

Автор: Charles Gide
Издательство: Bookwire
Серия:
Жанр произведения: Документальная литература
Год издания: 0
isbn: 4057664605085
Скачать книгу
tion>

       Charles Gide, Charles Rist

      A History of Economic Doctrines from the time of the physiocrats to the present day

      Published by Good Press, 2019

       [email protected]

      EAN 4057664605085

       BOOK I: THE FOUNDERS

       CHAPTER I: THE PHYSIOCRATS

       CHAPTER II: ADAM SMITH

       CHAPTER III: THE PESSIMISTS

       BOOK II: THE ANTAGONISTS

       CHAPTER I: SISMONDI AND THE ORIGINS OF THE CRITICAL SCHOOL

       CHAPTER II: SAINT-SIMON, THE SAINT-SIMONIANS, AND THE BEGINNINGS OF COLLECTIVISM

       CHAPTER III: THE ASSOCIATIVE SOCIALISTS

       CHAPTER IV: FRIEDRICH LIST AND THE NATIONAL SYSTEM OF POLITICAL ECONOMY

       CHAPTER V: PROUDHON AND THE SOCIALISM OF 1848

       BOOK III: LIBERALISM

       CHAPTER I: THE OPTIMISTS

       CHAPTER II: THE APOGEE AND DECLINE OF THE CLASSICAL SCHOOL. JOHN STUART MILL

       BOOK IV: THE DISSENTERS

       CHAPTER I: THE HISTORICAL SCHOOL AND THE CONFLICT OF METHODS

       CHAPTER II: STATE SOCIALISM

       CHAPTER III: MARXISM

       CHAPTER IV: DOCTRINES THAT OWE THEIR INSPIRATION TO CHRISTIANITY

       BOOK V: RECENT DOCTRINES

       CHAPTER I: THE HEDONISTS

       CHAPTER II: THE THEORY OF RENT AND ITS APPLICATIONS

       CHAPTER III: THE SOLIDARISTS

       CHAPTER IV: THE ANARCHISTS

       CONCLUSION

       INDEX

       Table of Contents

       Table of Contents

      Political Economy as the name of a special science is the invention of one Antoine de Montchrétien, who first employed the term about the beginning of the seventeenth century. Not until the middle of the eighteenth century, however, does the connotation of the word in any way approach to modern usage. A perusal of the article on Political Economy which appeared in the Grande Encyclopédie of 1755 will help us to appreciate the difference. That article was contributed by no less a person than Jean Jacques Rousseau, but its medley of politics and economics seems utterly strange to us. Nowadays it is customary to regard the adjective “political” as unnecessary, and an attempt is made to dispense with it by employing the terms “economic science” or “social economics,” but this article clearly proves that it was not always devoid of significance. It also reveals the interesting fact that the science has always been chiefly concerned with the business side of the State, especially with the material welfare of the citizens—“with the fowl in the pot,” as Henry IV put it. Even Smith never succeeded in getting quite beyond this point of view, for he declares that “the object of the political economy of every nation is to increase the riches and the power of that country.”[5]

      But the counsels given and the recipes offered for attaining the desired end were as diverse as they were uncertain. One school, known as the Mercantilist, believed that a State, like an individual, must secure the maximum of silver and gold before it could become wealthy. Happy indeed was a country like Spain that had discovered a Peru, or Holland, which, in default of mines, could procure gold from the foreigner in exchange for its spices. Foreign trade really seemed a quite inexhaustible mine. Other writers, who were socialists in fact though not in name—for that term is of later invention—thought that happiness could only be found in a more equal distribution of wealth, in the abolition or limitation of the rights of private property, or in the creation of a new society on the basis of a new social contract—in short, in the foundation of the Utopian commonwealth.

      

      It was at this juncture that Quesnay appeared. Quesnay was a doctor by profession, who now, when on the verge of old age, had turned his attention to the study of “rural economy”—the problem of the land and the means of subsistence.[6] Boldly declaring that the solution of the problem had always lain ready to hand, needing neither inventing nor discovering, he further maintained that all social relations into which men enter, far from being haphazard, are, on the contrary, admirably regulated and controlled. To those who took the trouble to think, the laws governing human associations seemed almost self-evident, and the difficulties they involved no greater than the difficulties presented by the laws of geometry. So admirable were these laws in every respect that once they were thoroughly known they were certain to command allegiance. Dupont de Nemours cannot be said to have exaggerated when, in referring to this doctrine, he spoke of it as “very novel indeed.”[7]

      It is not too much to say that this marks the beginning of a new science—the science of Political Economy. The age of forerunners is past. Quesnay and his disciples must be considered the real founders of the science. It is true that their direct descendants, the French economists, very inconsiderately allowed the title to pass to Adam Smith, but foreign economists have again restored it to