Just Trade. Berta Esperanza Hernández-Truyol. Читать онлайн. Newlib. NEWLIB.NET

Автор: Berta Esperanza Hernández-Truyol
Издательство: Ingram
Серия:
Жанр произведения: Юриспруденция, право
Год издания: 0
isbn: 9780814737446
Скачать книгу
of the entity concluding the agreement, however, it will not supersede a prior norm made with full authority.25 For example, a sole executive agreement concerning a trade embargo, which is a subject matter that constitutionally lies within the jurisdiction of Congress under the provision governing the regulation of commerce with foreign nations, will not be “later in time” so as to supersede a prior domestic law or a prior treaty.

      Finally, a brief note on federalism is appropriate. Because treaties and custom are within the federal government’s jurisdiction, any inconsistent state law or policy, regardless of whether it is earlier or later in time to the federal policy, will fail. Such was the fate of a Massachusetts law seeking to forbid trade with Burma because of that nation’s human rights record.26

      With these basic rules of international law and with some foundational interpretive tools for establishing the relationship between international and domestic norms, we now review the general concepts of trade (chapter 2), human rights (chapter 3), and their intersection (chapter 4). Subsequent chapters will study particular human rights in light of this extensive background.

      2

      Pillars and Escape Hatches

      Basic Concepts of International Trade Law in the Americas

       2.1 Overview of the GATT and WTO

      This chapter discusses the fundamental premises and economic underpinnings of the global trading system that are necessary for the reader to appreciate the varied interactions of trade and human rights law.1

      We described the General Introduction how trade law and human rights law developed along parallel tracks after the Second World War. The same horrors of war that inspired the founding of the United Nations and the development of modern human rights law, discussed in chapter 3, also led finance ministers of the world’s leading trading nations to gather in Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, in 1947 to establish global cooperative financial and economic institutions. Such an initiative was not entirely new; states have used rules to regulate trade at least since the Middle Ages in the form of bilateral treaties of navigation and commerce. The first serious attempt to create global economic rules, however, followed formation of the United Nations. The Bretton Woods system that resulted included the International Monetary Fund (IMF) to govern exchange rate policy and the World Bank to function as the central source for reconstruction and development funds. Trade ministers later fashioned the third leg of this economic and financial stool in Havana with the drafting of rules for transborder commercial relations.

      While it is not surprising that the Second World War’s human atrocities led to stronger rights of the individual in the form of human rights treaties, it is not quite so intuitive that the war’s nightmares also inspired economic change. The connection that world leaders perceived between the inferno that the world had just experienced and future economic policy among nation states was the severe inward turn toward protectionism during the late-1920s Great Depression. Leaders traced protectionist policies directly to the rise of fascist regimes in nations isolated after the First World War. The initial economic instrument, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), was seriously flawed. Critics noted aptly that it possessed neither sheriff nor jail, yet it succeeded in bringing together in a single document the basic rules to be applied when countries wished to restrict the free flow of goods across borders.

      The general rule was that trade was to be unrestricted, except in the specified situations, and under the enumerated conditions, described in the treaty. The exceptions included tariffs—border taxes—that the rules permitted Members to charge on a product’s importation. Other exceptions to unhindered trade involved the kinds of licenses with which Members could limit imports, the technical standards to which they could subject products, and the proper remedy for “unfairly traded” imports—dumped and subsidized goods.

      In 1995, almost half a century after the historic Bretton Woods meeting, trade ministers created the WTO as the umbrella organization to administer the nearly two dozen agreements that became annexes to its Charter. This marked completion of the process begun by the GATT to form both a central organization to administer global trade rules and a dispute settlement system to interpret them. Because of the WTO, and the seven wideranging rounds of multilateral GATT trade negotiations that preceded its creation, detailed WTO Agreements now provide an elaborate set of rules spanning a broad range of subjects to govern how Members must act in the global marketplace. Negotiators prescribed rules for trade in agriculture and in textiles and for national laws governing subsidies, dumping, intellectual property rights, investment, and customs procedures applied at the border. Ministers established detailed procedures for “safeguard” actions that Members may take temporarily to protect domestic industries from import surges, for border protections against unsafe or unsanitary products, and a separate agreement governing the mushrooming trade in services.

      (A) Introduction

      World trading rules are based on the concept of comparative advantage, described by British economist David Ricardo at a time nearly two hundred years ago when the sun never set on the British Empire. How does this theory help us understand why nations will export some products and import others, rather than simply producing all products domestically, which would render unnecessary any international trade?

      (B) Absolute Advantage

      In 1776 in The Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith introduced the theory of absolute advantage that set the stage for Ricardo’s brilliant and powerful further observation forty years later.2 Adam Smith analogized an individual worker to a country: If Worker A is more skilled than Worker B at making coats, and Worker B is more skilled than Worker A at making shoes, then Worker A will sell coats to Worker B and use the proceeds to purchase shoes from Worker B, rather than making both coats and shoes. It is cheaper—that is, more economically efficient—for Worker A to do so. We may say that Worker A has an absolute advantage over Worker B in the production of coats. By the same logic, Worker B has an absolute advantage over Worker A in the production of shoes.

      Analogously, if Country A’s climate is ideally suited for growing grapes, but its workforce is not sufficiently trained to assemble computer chips, whereas Country B has a highly trained labor force but is located in the far North—a climate unwelcoming to grapes—we may say that Country A has an absolute advantage, in relation to Country B, in the production of wine. Country B has an absolute advantage over Country A in the production of computer chips. Therefore, Country A should not make both wine and computer chips. Country A will find that it is “cheaper” to export wine to Country B in order to earn the foreign exchange needed to buy Country B’s computer chips. In this way, the income of both countries will be highest.

      In transitioning to Ricardo’s comparative advantage, it is important first to define “cheaper” in economic terms: Country A’s “opportunity costs” are lower. Opportunity cost describes the trade-offs that a country makes in choosing to produce with its finite resources one product instead of another; we may think of them as lost opportunities. So when we say that it is “cheaper,” or economically more efficient for Country A to produce wine rather than computer chips, we mean that Country A’s opportunity cost for making wine is lower than its opportunity cost for making computer chips. Country A will make fewer trade-offs in the production of wine than in the production of computer chips. Country A will use fewer of its finite resources.

      (C) Comparative Advantage

      To introduce David Ricardo’s contribution to the economics of trade, we may begin with a famous example used by economist Paul Samuelson to help us understand the comparative aspect of the theory. Suppose that a lawyer has created a court submission that must be typed and that she is a faster typist than any secretary she could hire. To use Adam Smith’s terms, she has an absolute advantage in both legal and typing work. Even though she