Information Wants to Be Shared. Joshua Gans. Читать онлайн. Newlib. NEWLIB.NET

Автор: Joshua Gans
Издательство: Ingram
Серия:
Жанр произведения: Экономика
Год издания: 0
isbn: 9781422190470
Скачать книгу
[3] Recordable cassette tapes were a threat to vinyl albums. I remember, as a ten-year-old, spending countless hours listening to the radio with two fingers ready to press “play and record” simultaneously on our family’s cassette deck so as to capture a desired song. (Yes, I do remember what songs, and, no, I’m not telling.) I did this because I couldn’t afford to purchase music (at least not often) and happily sacrificed time and quality to free it from broadcast radio. The current technologies for doing the same thing were a dream for those of my generation, but by the time they rolled around, I was too busy and comparatively too rich to live the fantasy.

      From this perspective, digitization should have wiped out the music industry. A decade ago, many predicted it would. Compact discs and physical music stores have pretty much disappeared. Even in the absence of piracy, this likely would have happened, as downloadable music was even more efficient to distribute and more valuable to consumers than CDs. Of course, consumers were well aware of this and took matters into their own hands.

      This is not the place to rehash the missteps of the music industry (both in its own digital ventures and in disproportionate legal responses to consumers), which, let’s face it, was well aware change was coming but it wasn’t sure where the competition was. A CD in 2000 sold for around $12. Given that a consumer’s purchases were typically driven by around four songs on the album, this would suggest a single song price of around $3. But a $3 single would have competed with the CD. It took Steve Jobs to convince the music industry that it was not competing with the $12 CD but rather with “free,” which suggested a much lower price point (as it turned out, $0.99). Moreover, the actual purchase had to be transactionally easier than illegal downloading. As learning how to download stuff illegally took some investment on the part of consumers (and risked infecting your PC with a nasty virus), a simple alternative (iTunes) convinced many consumers to not make that investment.

      Free and Business Models

      In less than a decade since the introduction of the iTunes Music Store, music publishers have abandoned digital rights management (DRM) entirely. One of the features that Apple offered the music industry in 2003 was its FairPlay system, which made copying music difficult. If you purchased a song on iTunes, you could transfer it to any iPod in your household, but it was harder to transfer it between computers and certainly beyond, although you could burn songs to a CD and then reimport them, DRM free. The overall rationale here was that use would be limited, as much as possible, to the individuals who made a purchase, just as it would be with physical media where some copying was possible.

      The answer is likely yes, precisely because music on iTunes is no longer shackled with DRM constraints. This migration happened as part of a compromise. Apple introduced a second pricing tier ($1.29) for songs without DRM and with a higher quality. Within a relatively short time, all the music on iTunes migrated to that form. Moreover, while the 30 percent price increase stuck in some cases, sometimes music publishers lowered prices. In 2011, Apple even offered iTunes Match, which allowed consumers who had not purchased music from iTunes (perhaps music they had downloaded illegally) to turn their collections into iTunes-quality versions.

      These changes reflect a third viewpoint of “information wants to be free”: use. When consumers acquire information, they want to be free to use it in a form they choose. This might mean transferring music between computers, but it also may mean editing a song to use in a home movie. This also makes information (in this case, music) more valuable, which is why, when constraints were lifted, the price of music could increase.

      This notion of free has important implications for the business models of information goods. From a consumer perspective, putting restrictions on the use of information increases the cost or decreases its value. Effectively, the producers are increasing the price without gaining any revenue. Indirectly, producers may be making piracy more costly, but, at the same time, these restrictions give consumers an incentive to avoid monetary payment if only to also avoid the hassle.

      Any price or restriction that does not reflect a seller’s costs of getting the marginal unit to market causes a corresponding loss in value created—what economists refer to as a deadweight loss. A deadweight loss occurs when a seller, in order to extract more from some consumers, either prices to exclude other consumers or to reduce overall use of the product. When the seller genuinely incurs costs, prices can play a role in getting consumers to share in the efforts to economize on those costs. However, for information goods, digitization reduces the need for such economizing and, correspondingly, increases the size and potential for deadweight losses.

      Traditional information businesses, when confronted with digital distribution, tend to start by replicating the same restrictions that consumers face in a physical world. They institute a system that maximizes deadweight losses. Instead, the “freedom to use” perspective suggests that sellers of information goods ought to start by envisaging their business as one where products are offered to consumers without restrictions on use—either through pricing or otherwise. Can they make a world without deadweight losses work? If they can, those consumers will pay for it, just as they paid more for digital music without DRM. And if this is the case, then far from being free, in terms of price, information wants something more.

      Paying for the Medium, Not the Message