But international power struggles are not just contested among national governments. As we note in the next chapter, after World War One financial interests and central bankers were quick to recover the reins of economic policy-making and advance their interests in the incipient multilateral arena. The result was an international economic regime tuned to the demands and wishes of footloose capital, ready and willing to employ austerity measures to fulfill them, and far too relaxed about the sharp rise in inequality, insecurity, and indebtedness this implied. These economic forces not only played a role in subverting the League of Nations’ fledgling efforts at international coordination as economic tensions began to mount toward the end of the 1920s, they also helped fuel the rise of right-wing populism, authoritarianism, depression, and, ultimately, war.
The international economic order imagined at Bretton Woods was designed to preclude a return to the chaos and despair of the 1930s. Its shape and practice would depend, critically, on how the United States employed its recently cemented hegemonic status. New political coalitions had brought Franklin D. Roosevelt to power in the 1932 election and put employment, economic security, and social justice at the center of the polis (Schlesinger 1958). Even as World War Two was still raging, the Roosevelt administration was intent on doing the same at the international level. The key to success, according to Henry Morgenthau, Roosevelt’s Secretary of the Treasury, and host of the Bretton Woods conference, was to drive “the usurious money lenders from the temple of international finance” and make capital serve “the general welfare” (Morgenthau 1944, 121). Morgenthau was unduly optimistic. Financial interests would soon push back against Roosevelt’s New Deal, opening up economic and legislative cracks and crevices both at home and in the international system. From the 1980s onwards they would assert ever greater influence over governments (and people) across the world.
Almost eighty years since Bretton Woods, the world we live in bears an uncomfortable resemblance to the one its delegates hoped would be gone forever. This has not been caused by right-wing populists such as Donald Trump, but by powerful interests who have rigged the rules of the economic game to maintain a winner-takes-all world of privileged individuals and corporations, in which the institutions of multilateral governance designed to foster responsible sovereignty and underpin social stability have instead curtailed the policy space available to governments and preached economic austerity (Mazower 2013: 421).
The operation (and breakdown) of that same system has, moreover, accelerated the climate crisis by undercutting the possibility of large-scale public investment, spreading feelings of political neglect, and deepening the sense of anxiety on which right-wing populists, who see climate change as a hoax, have fed. The global financial crisis of 2008–9 and the Covid-19 health and economic crises have exposed the fragilities of this system. The international community has, on both occasions, failed to respond appropriately.
This book makes the case for a fundamental resetting of the Bretton Woods institutions. By that we do not mean convening a three-week summit to tinker with the rules and treaties that govern international finance, trade, investment, and intellectual property. Nor, however, do we mean a wholesale abandoning of those institutions. Rather, building back better will require a renewal of public institutions and collective goals at the national level, along with new principles of international cooperation and global leadership, that together can rebalance the relationship between capital, labor, and the natural environment in a way that turns “prosperity for all” from prime-time sloganeering into the senso comune (common sense) of international economic cooperation.
The Takeaways from Bretton Woods 1.0
Efforts to reconcile the requirements of national governments with their international entanglements have a long history (Mazower 2013). What made Bretton Woods distinct from previous multilateral initiatives was a recognition that combining national economic goals with international peace and stability would require dedicated public institutions to ensure “the fullest and most effective use of the world’s resources.” The architects of these new institutions had to contend with three abiding and closely related challenges of global governance. First, how many resources and policy responsibilities could they procure from sovereign states to manage a supportive international environment (the sovereignty challenge)? Second, how would international policy priorities be set and responsibilities established across a diverse membership (the leadership challenge)? Third, how, if at all, would those who benefited the most from international cooperation compensate those who benefited the least (the distribution challenge)?
As will be further elaborated in the following chapters, there are four main takeaways from Bretton Woods that, we believe, remain relevant when thinking about governance in relation to contemporary global challenges:
1 Face up to failure. Austerity does not work; the gold standard and the outsized influence of financial interests had triggered widespread depression, insecurity, and conflict. A new order would require an ideological break with laissezfaire and adjustment through austerity.
2 Treat markets as means not ends. Economic security, personal safety, social justice, energy choices, and political representation should not be left to the dictates of markets. Prices and property rights can help to achieve more inclusive growth and development but require complementary institutions, effective regulation, and shared values that the market doesn’t itself provide.
3 Forge a set of shared national goals and common global interests. The international order was constructed to support the national goals of full employment and social welfare by providing five key global public goods: a stable monetary and exchange rate system; a global lender of last resort to provide liquidity to distressed nations; counter-cyclical and long-term lending; open markets’ including under recession; and a coordinated international economic policy.
4 Nurture cooperation. Rather than ad hoc summitry and bilateral policy negotiations, a set of permanent institutions is needed to monitor, coordinate, and guide the interdependent economic system into the future.
These ideas underpinned the creation of the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD), the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), and their subsequent extensions and offspring. While far from perfect, this was a powerful attempt to globalize economic relations while maintaining sufficient policy autonomy for nation states to pursue a broad set of economic and social goals.
In this book we make the case that a spirit similar to that of Bretton Woods needs to be evoked if the twenty-first-century global economy is to become more stable, more equitable, and environmentally sustainable. At the same time, the practice of multilateralism must change profoundly to meet these objectives, and with respect not only to its recent neoliberal deviation, but also to the original post-war multilateral model which relied unduly on American hegemony and was never able to properly accommodate development goals.
From Managing Capitalism to Enabling Capital
Financial interests were noticeable by their absence from the Bretton Woods conference. That was no accident. Disciplining the behavior of finance capital was seen, by the architects