Money. Geoffrey Ingham. Читать онлайн. Newlib. NEWLIB.NET

Автор: Geoffrey Ingham
Издательство: John Wiley & Sons Limited
Серия:
Жанр произведения: Экономика
Год издания: 0
isbn: 9781509526857
Скачать книгу
and how it should be counted. Notes and coins – cash – were an insignificant component of the money supply. But which of the other forms of money – bank accounts, deposits – and forms of credit – credit cards and private IOUs used in financial networks – should be included? Furthermore, many of the non-cash forms were beyond the control of the monetary authorities (see chapter 6).

      Despite monetary authorities’ many obvious practical and technical problems in conducting ‘monetary policy’ – essentially, attempting to control inflation – the long-run neutrality of money remains a core assumption of most mainstream economics. To believe otherwise – that money can be used as an independent creative force – is to suffer from the ‘money illusion’. As we shall see, the ‘illusion’ is to think that money has powers beyond its function as a simple instrument that only measures existing value and enables economic exchange. However, the centuries-old persistence and intensity of the unresolved disputes tells us that money is not merely this technical device to be managed by economic experts. Rather, it is also a source of social power to get things done (‘infrastructural power’) and to control people (‘despotic power’) (Ingham, 2004, 4). The ‘money question’ lies at the centre of all political struggles about the kind of society we want and how it might be achieved.

      1 money of account/measure of value: a numerical measure of value and for economic calculation; pricing offers of goods and debt contracts; recording income and wealth;

      2 a means of payment: for settling all debts that are denominated in the same money of account;

      3 a medium of exchange: something that can be exchanged for all other commodities;

      4 a store of value: a repository of purchasing and debt settling power, enabling deferment of consumption and investment or simply saving ‘for a rainy day’.

      This list is still found almost without exception in today’s textbooks. Its longevity gives the impression that the money question has been settled, but this is far from the case. Although it is obvious that money does these things, matters are not quite as simple as Walker had hoped. His solution masked the difficulties and confusions that had caused his and many others’ exasperation. Schumpeter correctly saw that the main reason for the unresolved disagreements was that the commodity and claim (credit) theories of money, including their respective ‘real’ and ‘monetary’ analyses, were by their very nature ‘incompatible’ (Schumpeter, 1917, 649). We should add that he also saw that the two theories were often inconsistent and contradictory, obscuring their differences and making ‘views on money as difficult to describe as shifting clouds’ (Schumpeter, 1994 [1954], 289). These theories are examined in the following chapter; here we need only note the basic differences.

      On the other hand, a minority rejected the view of the US Commission and held that money was precisely a ‘mental estimation’: that is, a socially and politically constructed abstract value (Del Mar, 1901). Soon after, in a critique of the dominant materialist conception of commodity money at the zenith of the gold standard era, Alfred Mitchell Innes concurred, declaring that “[t]he eye has never seen, nor the hand touched a dollar. All that we can touch or see is a promise to pay or satisfy a debt due for an amount called a dollar [which is] intangible, immaterial, abstract” (Mitchell Innes, 1914, 358). The dollar debt was settled by a token credit: that is, a means of payment which constituted a claim on goods offered for sale in a dollar monetary system. The existence of a debt gives money its value. As Georg Simmel explained, around the same time, in his sociological classic The Philosophy of Money, ‘[M]oney is only a claim upon society … the owner of money possesses such a claim and by transferring it to whoever performs the service, he directs him to an anonymous producer who, on the basis of his membership of the community, offers the required service in exchange for the money’ (Simmel, 1978 [1907], 177–8).

      Walker merely sidestepped the ‘incompatibility’ by smuggling